Notes on equilibrium and mechanisms

-

Introduction

An interior-point solver computes Walrasian (CEEI) prices and allocations from reported data but, taken alone, is not a mechanism—it is a centralized algorithm. By contrast, a (Walrasian) tâtonnement or auction process, in which prices are iteratively posted and agents submit demands that guide price updates, can be viewed as a decentralized mechanism whose limiting outcome is a Walrasian equilibrium (when it converges and agents are effectively price takers).

Hurwicz Impossibility (informational decentralization).

Hurwicz (1972) showed that for certain environments (e.g., with detrimental externalities, infinite horizons, nonconvexities) no finite–dimensional informationally decentralized process can be guaranteed to achieve Pareto efficiency for all economies—even if agents follow the rules truthfully. In such settings, coordinating solely via a bounded set of signals (“prices”) is fundamentally inadequate; some objectives cannot be reached by any finite‐message decentralized mechanism. 1

Interpretation.

An informationally decentralized mechanism lets each agent communicate only limited, local information (messages drawn from a finite‐dimensional space) rather than full preference/technology data. The impossibility says that, in the cited environments, any rule that always yields a Pareto‐satisfactory outcome must, somewhere, require unbounded (infinite) message dimension—or else fail to attain the goal. 1

Subsequent work used revelation principles to extend Hurwicz’s logic: when agents hold private information, classical Pareto optimality generally cannot be attained by incentive‐compatible (dominant‐strategy) direct mechanisms over rich domains. One must relax goals (e.g., approximate efficiency) or allow richer institutions 1 2

Incentives in Walrasian / CEEI Mechanisms.

Mechanism Design and Implementation

Mechanism design & implementation in an exchange market

Baseline economy.

Let $E = (I,{(X_i,\succeq_i,\omega_i)}_{i\in I})$. A Walrasian equilibrium is $(p^\ast,x^\ast)$ such that $\,x_i^\ast \in \arg\max{u_i(x_i): p^\ast!\cdot x_i \le p^\ast!\cdot\omega_i}$ for all $i$ and $\sum_i x_i^\ast=\sum_i\omega_i$.

Mechanism design.

Implementation question.

Does there exist a mechanism $g$ such that every equilibrium outcome equals the Walrasian correspondence $F(E)={\,(p,x)\text{ Walrasian in }E\,}$ under a chosen solution concept (dominant strategy, Nash, Bayesian)?

Comparison table.

Concept Exchange‐market interpretation
Benchmark Walrasian equilibrium $(p^\ast,x^\ast)$ derived from $(u_i,\omega_i)$.
Mechanism design Specify messages $M_i$ and rule $g$ to reach desirable allocations while respecting incentives.
Implementation theory Determine whether some $g$ exists whose equilibrium outcomes coincide exactly with all Walrasian allocations (or an approximate version).

Key facts.

What happens in a large exchange economy?

$\mathbf{x}= \mathcal{X}(\mathbf{p})$

References

  1. Leonid Hurwicz. On the concept and possibility of informational decentralization. The American Economic Review, 59(2):513–524, 1969.  2 3 4

  2. Eduardo M Azevedo and Eric Budish. Strategy-proofness in the large. The Review of Economic Studies, 86(1):81–116, January 2019.  2

  3. Donald John Roberts and Andrew Postlewaite. The incentives for price-taking behavior in large exchange economies. Econometrica, 44(1):115, January 1976. 

  4. Eric Budish. The combinatorial assignment problem: approximate competitive equilibrium from equal incomes. Journal of Political Economy, 119(6):1061–1103, 2011. 

  5. Gerard Debreu and Herbert Scarf. A limit theorem on the core of an economy. International Economic Review, 4(3):235–246, 1963. 

  6. Francis Ysidro Edgeworth. Mathematical Psychics: An Essay on the Application of Mathematics to the Moral Sciences. C. Kegan Paul & Co., 1881. 

  7. Dongdong Ge. Price taking notes. Course materials, 2024.